The University of Dublin | Trinity College -- Ollscoil Átha Cliath | Coláiste na Tríonóide
Trinity's Access to Research Archive
Home :: Log In :: Submit :: Alerts ::

TARA >
School of Business >
Business Studies >
Business Studies (Scholarly Publications) >

Please use this identifier to cite or link to this item: http://hdl.handle.net/2262/597

Title: Schumpeter, Business Cycles and Co-Evolution
Author: KINGSTON, WILLIAM
Author's Homepage: http://people.tcd.ie/wkngston
Keywords: Business Studies
Issue Date: 2006
Citation: William Kingston, Schumpeter, Business Cycles and Co-Evolution, Industry and Innovation, 13, 1, 2006, 97 - 106
Series/Report no.: Industry and Innovation
13
1
Abstract: In Business Cycles (1939) Schumpeter took up empirical data which had been produced by Kondratieff, and made the ‘‘clustering’’ of innovations into the actual cause of long economic cycles. The book was a failure, largely due to negative reviews which stressed the poor quality of its statistical analysis. In fact, an even more serious fault in it is its reflection of a near-total blind spot in Schumpeter’s perspective about the part played by law in economic life. He thought that ‘‘It is entirely immaterial whether or not [changes in the institutional framework] are embodied in, or recognized by, legislation.’’ The reality is that the concept of coevolution of technology and ways of doing business, on the one hand, and legal changes which affect the conditions for investment in them, on the other, explain long cycles much more persuasively than Schumpeter’s approach. It suggests that the first Kondratieff cycle was made possible by the availability of ‘‘full’’ property rights, the second by general limited liability law (which Schumpeter thought was ‘‘of comparatively small importance’’) and the third by new patent legislation which made corporate investment in R&D attractive. Schumpeter only discussed three cycles, but a co-evolutionary perspective makes it possible to envisage a fourth cycle as dependent upon the trademark laws which sustain advertising and mass markets, and a fifth one, in which the entertainment and information industries have been similarly underwritten by copyright law. The most plausible reason why Schumpeter undervalued laws was his attraction to the economic interpretation of history. According to this, laws, like ideas, are no more than reflections on a psychic level of social and economic realities, and have little or no power to shape these. For Keynes, in contrast, ‘‘it is ideas, not vested interests, that are dangerous for good or ill’’. There was consequently no place for co-evolution in Schumpeter’s thought. But what made him publish a book which he described as ‘‘a house which is not finished and furnished’’, when he did? It could be that the stimulus was evidence of the huge fame which Keynes’s General Theory was already winning.
Description: PUBLISHED
URI: http://hdl.handle.net/2262/597
Appears in Collections:Business Studies (Scholarly Publications)

Files in This Item:

File Description SizeFormat
CIAI_13_01_05.pdfpublished (publisher's copy) peer-reviewed128.11 kBAdobe PDFView/Open


This item is protected by original copyright


Please note: There is a known bug in some browsers that causes an error when a user tries to view large pdf file within the browser window. If you receive the message "The file is damaged and could not be repaired", please try one of the solutions linked below based on the browser you are using.

Items in TARA are protected by copyright, with all rights reserved, unless otherwise indicated.

 

Valid XHTML 1.0! DSpace Software Copyright © 2002-2010  Duraspace - Feedback